Chapter Info (Click Here)
Book No. – 8 (Modern India – History)
Book Name – British Rule in India and After (V.D. Mahajan)
What’s Inside the Chapter? (After Subscription)
1. Mayo’s Resolution (1870)
2. Lytton’s Change
3. Ripon (1882)
4. Curzon
5. Decentralisation Commission
6. Resolution of 1912
7. Meston Settlement
8. Reforms of 1935
9. New Constitution
Note: The first chapter of every book is free.
Access this chapter with any subscription below:
- Half Yearly Plan (All Subject)
- Annual Plan (All Subject)
- History (Single Subject)
- CUET PG + History
Decentralisation of Finance
Chapter – 24

Up to the passing of the Charter Act of 1833, princes enjoyed significant autonomy in financial matters.
The Charter Act of 1833 led to financial centralization, stating that no government could grant new offices, salaries, or allowances without the prior approval of the Governor-General.
Despite the passing of the Acts of 1853 and 1858, Indian finance remained centralized under the Government of India, with provinces having no authority over provincial revenues.
Provinces were merely managing agents for the Government of India, with all decisions on taxation, collection, and expenditure dictated from the headquarters.
The provinces had no control over tax collection, and all matters were decided by the central government.
Sir William Hunter described that, at the end of each year, local governments would present their expenditure estimates to the Governor-General-in-Council, who would approve the budget based on the expected revenue from all of India.
According to Strachey, the entire revenue from all provinces was treated as a single fund, and the Governor-General-in-Council alone authorized any expenditure.
Provincial governments had no discretion in sanctioning new charges and could not carry out improvements without approval from the Supreme Government.
Local governments could make administrative changes or alter land revenue assessments but could not spend money without formal approval.
Even small expenditures, like £20 for road repairs or wages for servants, required formal reporting and approval from the Government of India.
Critics noted that the distribution of public income became chaotic, resembling a scramble where the most aggressive had the advantage, with little focus on reason.
This system led to minimal local stimulus for economic growth or improvement, reducing the interest in developing public revenues.
It was widely acknowledged that the system was faulty and needed reform.
Efforts by General Dickens and Mr. Laing did not improve the situation.
In 1867, Strachey prepared a scheme to revise the system, and based on this, Lord Mayo initiated the first step towards decentralization.
Mayo’s Resolution (1870)
The Resolution of 1870 transferred control of several heads of expenditure to Provincial Governments, including Jails, Registration, Police, Education, Medical Services, Printing, Roads, Miscellaneous Public Improvements, and Civil Buildings.
Provincial governments were given the revenue from these areas along with a fixed annual Imperial Grant.
Any deficit was to be met by local taxation or by reducing expenditure.
If any portion of the allocated funds remained unspent by the end of the year, it would not lapse to the Central Government but remain with the Provincial Government.
Provincial Governments were allowed to create new appointments, provided the salary did not exceed Rs. 250 a month, and funds could be met from the assigned grants.
Lord Mayo’s government hoped the Resolution would promote care and economy, bring certainty into the fiscal system, and foster more harmony between the Supreme and Provincial Governments.
The operation of the Resolution was expected to provide opportunities for the development of self-Government, strengthen municipal institutions, and encourage greater association between natives and Europeans in administration.
A key defect in the system was that Imperial Grants were based on the expenditure levels of 1870-71, with no effort made to address existing inequalities or provide grants based on actual needs.
Dr. Gian Chand noted that provinces with lower levels of expenditure due to either access to the Central Government or their underdeveloped state were penalized for economy, unassertiveness, or backwardness.
R. C. Dutt criticized the reform for increasing the overall tax burden, with provinces imposing new land taxes to augment their revenues, which increased the State’s demand on the soil.
This increase went against the spirit of the Permanent Settlement in Bengal and violated the rules of limiting assessment to half the rental as per the 1855 and 1864 reforms.
However, it was pointed out that separating Central from Local taxation was common in modern states.
The system under Lord Mayo led to significant economy and efficiency.
According to Roberts, Lord Mayo found a serious deficit and left a substantial surplus, and improved the reliability of financial estimates, accounts, and statistics, making them punctual and full.